Journal article
American Journal of Political Science, vol. 54(3), 2010, pp. 718-736
APA
Click to copy
Gehlbach, S., Sonin, K., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2010). Businessman candidates. American Journal of Political Science, 54(3), 718–736. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2010.00456.x
Chicago/Turabian
Click to copy
Gehlbach, Scott, Konstantin Sonin, and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya. “Businessman Candidates.” American Journal of Political Science 54, no. 3 (2010): 718–736.
MLA
Click to copy
Gehlbach, Scott, et al. “Businessman Candidates.” American Journal of Political Science, vol. 54, no. 3, 2010, pp. 718–36, doi:10.1111/j.1540-5907.2010.00456.x.
BibTeX Click to copy
@article{gehlbach2010a,
title = {Businessman candidates},
year = {2010},
issue = {3},
journal = {American Journal of Political Science},
pages = {718-736},
volume = {54},
doi = {10.1111/j.1540-5907.2010.00456.x},
author = {Gehlbach, Scott and Sonin, Konstantin and Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina}
}
Why and when do businessmen run for public office rather than rely upon other means of influence? What are the implications of their participation for public policy? We show formally that "businessman candidacy" and public policy are jointly determined by the institutional environment. When institutions that hold elected officials accountable to voters are strong, businessmen receive little preferential treatment and are disinclined to run for office. When such institutions are weak, businessmen can subvert policy irrespective of whether they hold office, but they may run for office to avoid the cost of lobbying elected officials. Evidence from Russian gubernatorial elections supports the model’s predictions. Businessman candidates emerge in regions with low media freedom and government transparency, institutions that raise the cost of reneging on campaign promises. Among regions with weaker institutions, professional politicians crowd out businessmen when the rents from office are especially large.